Saturday, August 31, 2019

Cooperative Banks

WP/07/2 Cooperative Banks and Financial Stability Heiko Hesse and Martin Cihak  © 2007 International Monetary Fund WP/07/2 IMF Working Paper Monetary and Capital Markets Department Cooperative Banks and Financial Stability Prepared by Heiko Hesse and Martin Cihak1 Authorized for distribution by Mark W. Swinburne January 2007 Abstract This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF. The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy.Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate. Cooperative banks are an important, and growing, part of many financial systems. This paper empirically analyzes the role of cooperative banks in financial stability. Contrary to some suggestions in the literature, we find that cooperative banks are more stable than commercial banks. This finding is due to the lower volatil ity of the cooperative banks’ returns, which more than offsets their lower profitability and capitalization.This is most likely due to cooperative banks’ ability to use customer surplus as a cushion in weaker periods. We also find that in systems with a high presence of cooperative banks, weak commercial banks are less stable than they would be otherwise. The overall impact of a higher cooperative presence on bank stability is positive on average but insignificant in some specifications. JEL Classification Numbers: G21, P13 Keywords: financial sector stability, cooperative banks, commercial banks, savings banks Author’s E-Mail Address: [email  protected] org; [email  protected] rg 1 We are indebted to Klaus Schaeck for useful discussions during the early stages of the project. We also thank the following for their comments: Edward Al-Hussainy, Thorsten Beck, Ralf Elsas, Wim Fonteyne, Francois Haas, Patrick Honohan, Plamen Iossifov, Alain Ize, Barry Johnston, Luc Laeven, Eduardo Ley, Andrea Maechler, Paul Mills, John Muellbauer, Miguel Segoviano, Mark Swinburne, Alexander Tieman, and participants in an IMF seminar and a conference entitled â€Å"Public versus Private Ownership of Financial Institutions† in Frankfurt in November 2006. Contents Page I. Motivation and Literature Overview †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦.. 3 II. Data and Methodology †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦. 6 A. Data †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦ 6 B. Measuring Bank Stability†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦ C. Methodology †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦. 8 III. Results†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦.. 11 A. Decomposition of Z-Scores and Correlation Analysis †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦. 11 B. Regression Analysis †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦ 14 IV.Conclusions and Topics for Further Research†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦. 18 References†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦.. 35 Tables 1. Summary Statistics of Bank-Specific Variables in the Sample, 1994–2004 †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚ ¬ ¦ 20 2. Decomposition of Z-Scores for the Full Sample, 1994–2004 †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦. 21 3. Decomposition of Z-Scores for Selected Countries, 1994–2004†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦ 2 4. Sensitivity of the Z-score Decomposition†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦.. 23 5. Fitch: Long-Term Ratings: Distribution of the Banks in Sample†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦.. 24 6. Correlation Coefficients between the Z-Score and Selected Key Variables, 1994–2004†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦. 25 7. Regression Results (Full Sample)†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦.. 6 8. OECD Regressions with Governance Variable †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦.. 27 9. Regression Results (Large Banks) †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦. 28 10. Regression Results (Small Banks) †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦. 29 11. Robust Regressions†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â ‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦ 30 12.Quantile Regressions (Full Sample) †¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦. 31 Figure 1. Cooperative Banks: Retail Market Shares in Selected Countries†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦.. 3 Appendix I. Data Issues†¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦Ã¢â‚¬ ¦ 32 3 I. MOTIVATION AND LITERATURE OVERVIEW Cooperative (mutual ) banks are an important part of many financial systems. 2 In a number of countries, they are among the largest financial institutions when considered as a group.Moreover, the share of cooperative banks has been increasing in recent years; in the sample of banks in advanced economies and emerging markets analyzed in this paper, the market share of cooperative banks in terms of total banking sector assets increased from about 9 percent in the mid-1990s to about 14 percent in 2004. Cooperative banks are particularly numerous and large in Europe. The five largest cooperative banks in the European Union (EU) rank among the EU’s top 25 banking groups in terms of consolidated equity.Reflecting the cooperative banks’ focus on retail banking, their market share in retail business is even more substantial: for example, five EU member countries have more than a 40 percent market share of cooperative banks in terms of branch networks (Figure 1). In non-European advanced economies and emerging markets, the share of cooperative banks is generally lower, but there are several countries where they play a non-negligible role. 3 Figure 1. Cooperative Banks: Retail Market Shares in Selected Countries 70 Percent of all branches 60 50 40 30 20 10 Netherlands Finland Germany Portugal 0 Austria France Spain Greece ItalySource: OECD’s Bank Profitability Report; and authors’ calculations. We use the term â€Å"cooperative bank† to include also credit unions. The main distinctive feature of credit unions is that their customers are identical with members. In other cooperative banks, not all customers are members. For more background on institutional history and structure of cooperative (mutual) banking, see Fonteyne (forthcoming) and Cuevas and Fischer (2006). 3 2 4 The importance of cooperative banks—and in particular the implications of their specific nature for financial stability—has not yet received appropriate attention in the emp irical literature.The literature devotes disproportionately little attention to cooperative banks in comparison with commercial banks, smaller than would correspond, for example, to their market share. For example, only about 0. 1 percent of all banking-related entries in EconLit, a major database of economic research, relates to cooperative banking. 4 This contrasts with the share of cooperative banks, which account on average for about 10 percent of banking system assets in advanced economies and emerging markets, reaching as much as 30 percent in some countries in terms of assets (and even more in terms of branches—see Figure 1).Most of the EconLit entries devoted to cooperative banks deal with specific country cases or with issues relating to efficiency rather than those relating to financial stability. For example, Brunner and others (2004) analyze revenue and cost efficiency of cooperative banks in France, Germany, Italy, and Spain, finding that cooperative banks are no t less effective at managing revenues and costs than commercial banks. The regulatory framework, including the recent amendments, is also generally designed with commercial banks in mind.For example, the third pillar of the New Basel Capital Accord (Basel II)—which relies on extensive disclosure to ensure that banks are subject to market discipline—has significantly reduced effectiveness in the case of cooperative banks (Fonteyne, 2007). Cooperatives’ disclosure practices and requirements are substantially below those of commercial banks, especially listed ones. Even if disclosure were adequate, there are rarely markets that could exert effective disciplining pressure.Shareholder pressure cannot be relied upon and cooperatives do not rely much on interbank markets or debt issuance as sources of funds. Finally, loyal and insured retail depositors are not likely to exert an effective market disciplining effect either at an early enough stage. Macroprudential work on financial systems, such as the IMF’s Financial System Stability Assessment reports (FSSAs), Article IV staff reports, and the Global Financial Stability Report, as well as reports on financial stability published by central banks (for a survey, see Cihak, 2006) pay relatively little attention to cooperative banks.Fonteyne (forthcoming) cites the FSSAs for France and Germany as two reports that devoted some attention to cooperative banks; however, the references to cooperative banks in those reports focused on mutual support and deposit insurance mechanisms, efficiency, and financial sector consolidation issues, rather than on financial stability implications.Several authors have noted in passing the potential of cooperative banks to increase the fragility of financial systems. For example, commenting on a finding by Barth, Caprio, and A search of the EconLit database was carried out on June 15, 2006, looking for all entries that had â€Å"banks† or â€Å"bankingâ⠂¬  among keywords or in the abstract. A search was then run for those that referred to â€Å"cooperative banks,† â€Å"cooperative banking,† or â€Å"mutual financial institution(s). † 4 5Levine (1999) that a higher degree of government ownership of banks tends to be associated with higher fragility of financial systems, Goodhart (2004) interprets this result as perhaps indicating that the presence of any non-profit-maximizing banking entities may make financial systems more fragile. Goodhart does not elaborate on the underlying mechanism of this relationship between the presence of non-profit-maximizing entities and financial stability, but possible mechanisms are not difficult to envision in the case of cooperative banks.Cooperative banks’ stated objective is not to maximize profits, but rather their members’ consumer surplus; this is in some cases complemented by additional objectives that seek to contribute to the well-being of stakeholders o ther than member-consumers, such as employees. 5 If a cooperative bank’s pursuit of objectives other than profit maximization results in very low profitability, its balance sheet risks grow faster than its capital, leading to deteriorating solvency.If cooperative banks accept lower profitability as the price to pay for delivering financial services at below-market prices to retail clients, they may pull down the profitability of the banking system, with negative repercussions for other banks’ soundness. The literature’s verdict on cooperative banks’ role in financial stability is less than clear. Several papers suggest that cooperative banks may have more difficulties adjusting to adverse circumstances and changing risks.For example, Brunner and others (2004) note that the Swedish cooperative banking sector did not survive the crisis of the early 1990s in a cooperative form, as it faced high marginal costs of capital—the need to restore capital was a major factor in the decision to demutualize. Fonteyne (forthcoming) suggests that cooperative banks may be more vulnerable to shocks in credit quality and interest rates, because they are more focused on traditional financial intermediation than other institutions, and therefore have higher exposures to credit and interest rate risk.At the same time, several studies suggest that cooperative banks have generally lower incentives to take on risks. For example, Hansmann (1996) and Chaddad and Cook (2004) find that mutual financial institutions in the United States tend to adopt less risky strategies than demutualized ones. Whether cooperative banks have a positive or negative impact on financial stability therefore remains an empirical question. We address this question by analyzing individual bank data for major advanced economies and emerging markets. We examine two related issues:In addition, some authors have suggested that due to relatively less oversight by members, as opposed to owners in a commercial bank, managers in cooperative banks may be more likely to pursue their own goals (e. g. , â€Å"empire building†) rather than members’ interests, potentially hurting their stability. Fonteyne (forthcoming) discusses cooperative banks’ objective functions in more details and summarizes the relevant literature. 5 6 †¢ Cooperative banks’ soundness and resilience to stress. We test the hypothesis that cooperative banks are relatively weaker in responding to stress because of the features of their business model.Cooperative banks’ impact on other banks. We test the hypothesis that the presence of cooperative banks reduces the stability of other banks. As explained, this may be, for example, because the cooperative banks use their lower average cost of capital to pursue aggressive expansion plans that may weaken other financial institutions. †¢ The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section II introduces the data and variables used in the paper (characterized in more detail in Appendix I), and presents the estimation methodology. Section III presents the empirical results.Section IV sums up the conclusions, and suggests topics for further research. II. DATA AND METHODOLOGY A. Data Our calculations are based on individual bank data drawn from the BankScope database, provided by Bureau van Dijk. We use data on all commercial, cooperative, and savings banks in the database from 29 major advanced economies and emerging markets that are members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 6 In total, we have data on 16,577 banks from 1994 to 2004, comprising 11,090 commercial banks, 3,072 cooperative banks, and 2,415 savings banks.Several general issues relating to the BankScope data need to be mentioned. First, the database, while being the most comprehensive commercially available database of banking sector data, is not exhaustive. Coverage varies from country to country; for most countries in our sample, the BankScope data cover 80 to 90 percent of the total banking system assets, and the coverage of cooperative banks is lower than for commercial banks (in particular, only a small number of cooperative banks is included in the United States). However, the coverage of our paper is still higher than in most banking studies (and in particular studies that focus on banks with particular features, such as large banks or banks that are listed on stock market), and even for cooperative banks our sample captures a majority in terms of total assets. We therefore believe the sample is comprehensive enough to make reliable inferences. 6 7 See Appendix I for a list of the OECD member countries.Also, our sample does not cover some specialized types of banking institutions, such as development banks or specialized investment companies (even though our analysis covers, for example, investment banking activities carried out by commercial banks on their balance sheet). 7 Second, BankScope gives the specialization (status) of a bank in the sample (commercial, cooperative, and savings) in the current year. Therefore, it is for instance likely that the commercial bank subset contains some banks that have been cooperative or savings banks in earlier periods.Where information was available, we adjusted the status of a bank accordingly. For example, France was subject to a banking reform in June 1999 in which all savings banks were converted into cooperative banks. The Alliance & Leicester (United Kingdom) as well as First National (Ireland) Building Societies were demutualized and were stock market listed in 1997 and 1998, respectively. Given the large number of banks in the sample, it was not possible to individually check potential changes in specialization over time. However, we do not think that this limitation of the BankScope dataset biases the results.Third, our analysis is based on unconsolidated bank statements. Ideally, we wou ld have opted for consolidated statements whereby the parent company integrates the statements of its subsidiaries. However, given that about 90 percent of BankScope observations for the selected countries and periods are based on unconsolidated data, we focus on results based on unconsolidated data. Nonetheless, we have also performed the same calculations with consolidated data, and obtained very similar results (available upon request). In addition to the bank-by-bank data, we also use a number of macroeconomic and other system-wide indicators.Those are described in more detail in Appendix I. B. Measuring Bank Stability Our primary dependent variable is the z-score as a measure of individual bank risk. The zscore has become a popular measure of bank soundness (see Boyd and Runkle, 1993; Maechler, Mitra, and Worrell, 2005; Beck and Laeven, 2006; Laeven and Levine, 2006; and Mercieca, Schaeck, and Wolfe, forthcoming). Its popularity stems from the fact that it is directly related t o the probability of a bank’s insolvency, i. e. , the probability that the value of its assets becomes lower than the value of the debt.The z-score can be summarized as z? (k+ µ)/? , where k is equity capital as percent of assets,  µ is average after-tax return as percent on assets, and ? is standard deviation of the after-tax return on assets, as a proxy for return volatility. The z-score measures the number of standard deviations a return realization has to fall in order to deplete equity, under the assumption of normality of banks’ returns. A higher z-score corresponds to a lower upper bound of insolvency risk—a higher z-score therefore implies a lower probability of insolvency risk. For banks listed in liquid equity markets, a popular version of the z-score is distance-to-default, which uses stock price data to estimate the volatility in the economic capital of the bank (Denmark National Bank, 2004). 8 (continued†¦) 8 One issue relating to the use o f z-scores for analyzing cooperative banks is whether the zscores are a fair measure of soundness across different groups of institutions, in particular given that cooperative banks are much less focused on returns and profitability than commercial banks.We think that the z-score is an objective measure, as all banks (cooperative, commercial, and savings), face the same risk of insolvency in case they run out of capital. This is exactly the risk captured by the z-score, which has the same methodology for any type of bank. If an institution â€Å"chooses† to have lower risk-adjusted returns, it can still have the same or higher z-score if it has a higher capitalization. C.Methodology We start by two preliminary steps: a decomposition of observed differences in z-scores into the underlying factors (capitalization, returns, and volatility of returns), and a calculation of correlation coefficients between z-scores and other variables of interest. The main part of our approach is to test the two hypotheses outlined in the introduction (Section I) using regressions of z-scores on a number of explanatory variables. We estimate a general class of panel models of the form z i , j ,t = ? + ? Bi , j ,t ? 1 + ? I j ,t ? 1 + ? ? s Ts + ? ? s Ts I j ,t ? 1 + ? ? s Ts Bi , j ,t ? 1 + ?M j ,t ? 1 + ? ? j C j + ? ? t Dt + ? i , j ,t where the dependent variable is the z-score z i , j ,t for bank i in country j and at time t; Bi , j ,t ? 1 is a vector of bank-specific variables; I jt ? 1 are time-varying banking industry-specific variables in country j; Ts , Ts I j ,t ? 1 and Ts Bi , j ,t ? 1 are the type of banks and the interaction between the type and some of the industry-specific variables as well as bank-specific variables, respectively; M j ,t , C j , and Dt are vectors of macroeconomic variables, country, and yearly dummy variables, respectively; and ? i , j ,t is the residual.To distinguish the impact of bank type on the z-score, we include two dummy variables. T he first dummy variable takes the value of 1 if the bank in question is a commercial bank, and 0 otherwise; the second one takes the value of 1 for savings banks, and 0 otherwise. If cooperative banks are relatively weaker than commercial (or savings) banks, the first (second) dummy variable would have a positive sign in the regression explaining z-scores. For most cooperative banks, however, market price data are not available. This paper therefore relies on the specification of the z-score that relies only on accounting data. At the systemic (country) level, we want to examine cooperative banks’ impact on other banks and the hypothesis that the presence of cooperative banks lowers systemic stability. For this reason, we have calculated the market share of cooperative banks by assets for each year and country and interacted it with the commercial bank dummy. For example, a negative sign of the sum of the coefficients of the cooperative banks’ market share and its inte raction with the commercial bank dummy would indicate a decrease in commercial banks’ stability (in their z-scores).In addition to these key variables of interest, the regression includes a number of other control variables, both on individual bank level and on country level. Appendix I provides a description of the variables. To control for bank-level differences in bank size, asset composition, and cost efficiency, we include the bank’s asset size in billions of U. S. dollars, loans over assets, and the cost-income ratio. Also, to control for differences in structure of banks’ income, we calculate a measure of income diversity that follows Laeven and Levine (forthcoming). The variable measures the degree to which banks diversify from traditional lending activities (those generating net interest income) to other activities. To further capture differences of cooperative banks in their business orientation, we interact the income diversity variable with the coope rative bank dummy. Controlling for these variables is important because there are differences in these variables between cooperative banks and the other groups. For example, commercial banks are on average larger than cooperative banks throughout the sample period.Similarly, the asset size of cooperatives is less volatile than for commercial banks but significantly more volatile than for savings banks. We want to adjust for the differences in these variables to ensure that we capture the â€Å"pure† impact of the bank’s legal form (commercial, cooperative, or savings) on stability. 10 Table 1 shows the summary statistics of the bank-specific variables by type of bank. On the country level, we also adjust for the impact of the macroeconomic cycle by including a number of macroeconomic variables (GDP growth rate, inflation, the real long-term interest rate, and exchange rate appreciation).To account for cross-country variation in z-scores caused by differences in market concentration, we include the Herfindahl index, defined as the sum of squared market shares (in terms of total assets) of all banks in the country. 11 9 The income diversity measure is defined as 1 ? (Net interest income ? Other operating income ) . Higher values of Total operating income the variable correspond to a higher degree of diversification. 10For completeness, we have also tested whether the impact of bank-specific variables such as asset size is different for the different types of banks (by multiplying the asset size with the relevant dummy variables), but this has not led to any significantly robust results. We do not have a strong prior on the impact of the Herfindahl index, because the existing literature contains two contrasting views on the relationship between concentration and stability. For example, Allen and Gale (2004) put forth theoretical arguments why more concentrated markets are likely to be more stable, and Beck, 11 (continued†¦) 0 In separate regres sions, we account for the quality of corporate governance in a country, using a popular indicator by Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2005). The authors provide six governance measures (voice and accountability, political stability, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law, and control of corruption). We average the six measures across the available years (2004, 2002, 2000, 1998, and 1996) into one single index per country. The governance indicator should capture cross-country differences in institutional developments that might have an effect on banking risk.All bank-specific and macroeconomic variables, the Herfindahl index, and the cooperatives’ market share and its interaction with the commercial bank dummy are lagged to capture possible past effects of these variables on the banks’ risk. We also test for the robustness of the lagged effects by restricting the explanatory variables to contemporaneous effects. Across the whole sample, most observatio ns of the z-score are found in the 20–80 range; however, there are some extreme observations, resulting in the sample range being from -81 to 14,811 with an average of 57.This leads to the question whether to eliminate observations at the extreme end of the z-score distribution. On one hand, we are interested in situations of instability, and therefore would like to include extreme observations; on the other hand, some of the extreme observations may be due to very specific, one-off events, or sometimes data errors. To assess the robustness of our results with respect to the outliers, we have done all the calculations both for the full sample and for a sample that excludes the most extreme outliers.To keep the presentation succinct, this paper presents results for a sample that eliminates the 1st and 99th percentile from the distribution of the z-score. The results for the full sample including those extreme outliers are available from the authors; the main conclusions are th e same for both approaches. To further assess the robustness of the results with respect to the selected sample, we estimate the same regression for different country samples, and different bank size samples. We start with the widest sample that includes all OECD countries (except Slovakia, for which the BankScope contains no data on cooperative banks).We then estimate the same regression for the Euro area (EU12),12 and for countries where the cooperatives’ market share Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (2005) provide empirical results consistent with the view that more concentration is associated with more financial stability. Contrary to these findings, for example, Boyd and de Nicolo (forthcoming) and Mishkin (1999) suggest that too concentrated systems can be characterized by increased risktaking behavior by banks. 12 We have also carried out all the estimates for EU15 countries (EU12, Denmark, Sweden, and the United Kingdom).The results have not been substantially different from those for EU12 and are therefore not reported here. Nonetheless, they are available from authors upon request. 11 exceeds 5 percent in our sample (Coop5). 13 As regards the robustness with respect to bank size, we estimate the regressions separately for large and small banks. We also test the robustness of our results with respect to the estimation methods. We start by pooled ordinary least squares (OLS) and fixed effects estimates, followed by a robust estimation technique, and a quantile regression.The robust estimation technique assigns, through an iterative process, lower weights to observations with large residuals, thereby making the estimation less sensitive to outliers. The quantile regression allows to address the question whether the factors that cause high fragility are systematically different from the factors that cause medium or low fragility. We would like to stress that our analysis is based on individual banks’ z-scores. The impacts calculated from the estim ated regressions are average impacts per bank.This approach provides a baseline assessment of stability and is frequent in the literature. However, to arrive at a more complete assessment of systemic stability, one needs to look also at correlation of losses across defaults and losses given default—a topic for further research. III. RESULTS A. Decomposition of Z-Scores and Correlation Analysis A preliminary analysis shows that the cooperative banks’ z-scores are on average significantly higher than for commercial banks (and slightly, but insignificantly, higher than for savings banks), suggesting that cooperative banks are more stable than commercial banks.Interestingly, this is not because of capitalization or profitability—those two are on average weaker for cooperative banks than for commercial banks. The result is driven by the fact that the cooperative banks’ standard deviation of returns is much lower, resulting in the high zscore (Tables 2 and 3). Why do we find the low volatility of returns over time in cooperative banks? A plausible explanation is that the cooperative banks use the customer surplus as a first line of defense in weaker times.Cooperative banks pass on an important part of their returns to customers in the form of surplus. Indeed, their stated objective is not maximization of profits, but rather maximization of the consumer surplus. This leaves the cooperative banks with relatively low average return ratios in normal years. However, in weaker years, they are able to extract some of the consumer surplus, thereby mitigating the negative impact of stress on returns. 13 The Coop 5 countries are Austria, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Netherlands and the United Kingdom. 12We are therefore observing a lower variability of returns in cooperative banks than in commercial banks (and about the same as in savings banks). 14 In other words, our calculations suggest that the consumer surplus can be viewed as the first line of defense for cooperative banks, in a similar way as profits are the first line of defense for commercial banks. However, there are some important differences. First, consumer surplus is a very complex concept to measure. We are not able to observe consumers’ surplus on a consistent basis; even though we can make inferences about it from the pattern of returns.Second, while undistributed profits can be relatively easily used to replenish capital, extracting consumer surplus is one more step removed from capital and requires time. To address the idea that cooperative banks are less able to raise capital in situations of stress, we have also examined volatility in cooperative banks’ capitalization compared with commercial banks’ capitalization (even though volatility in capitalization is not a part of the z-score calculation). The results only onfirm our findings about z-scores, because cooperative banks also have a significantly lower volatility of capitalizati on. The finding that cooperative banks have higher z-scores is novel, but not inconsistent with the existing literature. The empirical papers on the subject note that cooperative banks have lower reported returns, but they find no compelling evidence that the lower returns would be due to a less effective management of revenues and costs than in commercial banks (e. g. , Brunner and others, 2004; and Altunbas, Evans, and Molyneux, 2001). 5 If the lower returns were due to inefficiencies in cooperative banks’ operation, then it would be difficult to argue that there are cushions that can be used in weak times. However, the finding that cooperative banks have lower returns with the same efficiency suggest that there are cushions that can be used in situation of stress, an idea that is consistent with our finding. 16 We also find no evidence for our sample that cooperative banks are less efficient than commercial banks in terms of the cost-income ratio (Table 1).To assess the ro bustness of our findings, we have also tried some alternatives to the standard definition of the z-score (Table 4). The underlying idea behind these alternative approaches (which have to our knowledge not yet been discussed in the literature) is that the standard An additional explanation of the lower volatility of returns can be the networks that cooperative banks form to provide a safety net. However, these support mechanisms are typically triggered only in extreme stress, and are therefore likely to explain only a small part of the observed difference in the volatility of returns. 5 14 The finding about lower returns is in contrast with previous observation by Valnek (1999), who finds that mutual building societies in the United Kingdom have higher returns and risk-adjusted returns on assets than commercial banks. In a recent paper, Mercieca, Schaeck, and Wolfe (forthcoming) estimate an equation for z-scores in a sample of small European banks, including small cooperative banks, but their estimated slope coefficient for a cooperative bank dummy is insignificant. 16 13 deviation underlying the z-score gives only a part of the information about the behavior of zscores.In particular, when assessing stability, we are much more interested in the downward spikes in returns on assets (ROAs) and z-scores than in the upticks. Table 3 has four panels, corresponding to four alternative variables that we have investigated, in particular: †¢ We have defined downward (upward) volatility of ROA as the sample average of the difference between the bank-specific ROA per year and its mean of ROA if the ROA is below (above) the bank-specific mean. Table 4 indicates that both downward and upward volatility of ROA are higher for commercial banks than for cooperative and savings banks.Comparing the absolute values within each bank type shows that the commercial banks' downward volatility of ROA is higher than its upward volatility. This finding does not hold for cooperative and savings banks. Similarly, we have defined the downward (upward) volatility of the z-scores as the sample average of the difference between the bank-specific z-score per year and its mean of the z-score if the z-score is below (above) the bank-specific mean. We cannot observe any statistical difference in the downward (upward) volatility of the z-scores.Furthermore, the downward (upward) volatility of the capitalization is defined as the sample average of the difference between the bank-specific equity-to-assets ratio per year and its mean of the capitalization if the equity-to-assets ratio is below (above) the bankspecific mean. The downward (upward) volatility of capitalization is lower for cooperatives than for commercial and savings banks. Commercial banks’ z-scores have a higher frequency in the lower distribution of the zscores than cooperative and savings banks.This supports the previous results of lower average z-scores for commercial banks during the sample period . †¢ †¢ †¢ Overall, the above robustness checks support the findings for the simple z-scores. 17 To further assess the robustness of our findings, we can also look at measures of financial soundness that are alternative to the z-scores. An obvious alternative are ratings by rating agencies. Table 5 presents a distribution of long-term credit ratings by the Fitch Ratings for cooperative banks and commercial banks in the 29 advanced economies and emerging markets.The overall conclusion is that at least on the first look there does not seem to be a major difference between the ratings for cooperative banks and commercial banks. For both groups, for example, about 90 percent of institutions have investment grade long-term credit 17 We have also calculated a modified z-score, defined as capitalization plus the ROA over the absolute value of the downward volatility of ROA. Results for this modified z-score confirm that on average, cooperative banks are more stable than comm ercial banks, reinforcing the findings from the above robustness tests.The results do not change qualitatively whether we use the absolute value of downward/upward deviation from the mean for the volatilities of the ROA, z-score and capitalization measures, or whether we use the squared downward/upward deviation from the mean. 14 rating (defined as BBB- or higher). It should be noted, however, that the distribution of ratings for cooperative banks is highly influenced by the ratings for German cooperative banks, all of which were given the same (A+) rating. This limits the usefulness of ratings for further, econometric analysis.In the next section, we will therefore focus on the z-scores. Before discussing the regression results, we provide correlation coefficients between the zscore and selected key variables in Table 6. Here, we differentiate between all the banks in the sample and large (small) banks that have assets larger (smaller) than US$1 billion. Similar to the findings fro m the decomposition of the z-score in Table 1, commercial banks tend to have lower z-scores than cooperative and savings banks in all model specifications.Also, both the cooperative bank dummy and the z-score are positively correlated across the different samples. While there is no evidence that the cooperative market share per country and year is negatively correlated with the z-scores of all commercial, cooperative and savings banks, we do find a significantly negative correlation between the z-scores and the interaction term of the share of cooperatives and commercial bank dummy in all models as hypothesized previously.A stronger cooperative sector is associated with higher commercial banks’ risk. Since correlation findings do not necessarily reflect causal relationships and do not account for other control factors, we now turn to the panel regressions. B. Regression Analysis Table 7 presents pooled OLS and fixed effects estimates for the z-scores in the full sample of ban ks in OECD countries, in the Euro zone (EU12), and the countries where the cooperatives’ market share exceeds 5 percent (Coop5). 8 All panel regressions include clustered standard errors (by bank), year and country dummy variables. Our main focus in discussing the results is on the two hypotheses outlined in the introduction, namely that cooperative banks are weaker and that their presence reduces the stability of other banks. All the pooled OLS regressions provide strong evidence that cooperative banks have higher z-scores than commercial and savings banks.The estimated signs of the commercial bank dummy and savings bank dummy are negative in all the pooled OLS and fixed effects regressions (and significant at the 10 percent level in all but one the regressions). That is, cooperative banks appear less likely to become insolvent than the other two bank types. This 18 In general, it is not possible to identify the commercial and savings bank dummies in the fixed effects regres sions since they are not time-varying. Since we have changed the status of a few banks as discussed before, we could in principle identify the bank dummies.But we do omit the commercial and savings bank dummies in the fixed effects estimations, as only a few dummies are time-varying, and therefore the coefficients and p-values might not be very meaningful. 15 is in line with the findings from the decomposition of the z-score in the previous section. It strengthens the previous findings, because the conclusion about higher z-scores in cooperative banks holds even if we adjust for other explanatory factors, such as the fact that cooperative banks are typically more retail-oriented than commercial banks.As regard the impact of a higher presence of cooperative banks on banking stability, the first approximation is provided by the estimated slope coefficient of the â€Å"share of cooperatives† variable, which is positive and significant in all but one specification. Based on this estimated slope coefficient, we can say that a higher share of cooperative banks increases stability (measured by z-score) of an average bank in the same banking system. It is important to stress, however, that this is only an average effect based on all the commercial, cooperative, and savings banks in the sample. 9 To analyze in more detail the cooperative banks’ impact on other (e. g. , commercial) banks, one needs to analyze the sum of the coefficients of (i) the share of cooperative banks and (ii) the interaction of the share of cooperative banks with the other bank (e. g. , commercial bank) dummy. Looking again at the estimates in Table 7, and focusing on commercial banks, we find that a higher market share of cooperative banks has a significantly negative effect on commercial banks’ risk in the pooled OLS model for OECD countries.This would be consistent with the hypothesis that a higher presence of not-profit-maximizing cooperative banks could pull down the sou ndness of commercial banks. This could be because cooperative banks â€Å"over-pay† for deposits or â€Å"under-charge† for assets, or because the commercial banks get crowded out of the retail market and have to turn to markets that are more volatile. 20 However, this finding does not hold for the other model specifications. There is thus some, but limited, evidence in support of Goodhart’s (2004) hypothesis in the full sample. 1 The other explanatory variables have the expected signs. In particular, we find that larger banks tend to have lower z-scores, perhaps because they engage in riskier activities than smaller banks (and reflecting a relatively higher risk aversion of small banks). Also, banks with higher loan-to-asset ratios tend to be riskier (even though this result is valid only for the 19 If we measured a â€Å"portfolio z-score† of the banking system, it would increase even more than the average zscore, due to the simple fact that a higher ma rket share of cooperative banks means a higher share of banks with higher -scores. However, our approach in this analysis is derived from individual bank z-scores. To examine the hypothesis that cooperative banks over-pay for deposits or under-charge for loans, we have calculated the implicit deposit and lending rates for the commercial and cooperative banks, defining the implicit deposit rate as total interest rate expenses over deposits and the lending rate as interest rate income over loans. Based on this calculation, there is no significant difference for deposit rates, but there is some evidence that cooperative banks charge lower lending rates than commercial banks (9. percent compared with 13. 2 percent). 21 20 For savings banks, the impact of a higher cooperative bank share is insignificant and not reported in Table 7. 16 OECD sample as a whole, but not necessarily in the EU12 and Coop5 sub-samples). Banks with higher loan portfolios on their balance sheets relative to their total assets might be more likely to experience problems with non-performing loans and thus be riskier. Finally, inefficient banks in terms of their cost-to-income ratio are less likely to cover their costs when hit by adverse shocks, so they tend to be riskier.The evidence on the effect of bank concentration on individual bank risk is mixed and unclear in the pooled OLS and fixed effects regressions. The results from the income diversity variable and its interaction with the cooperative bank dummy support the above hypothesis. Overall, an increase in diversity (which could be interpreted as less focus on the traditional lending business) tends to increase banks’ risk; however, cooperative banks tend to become more stable if they diversify their activities (sum of the coefficients of the income diversity variable and its interaction with the cooperative bank dummy).This result can be explained by the fact that commercial banks are about 30– 40 percent more diversified than cooperative banks (both in the whole OECD sample and the EU12 and Coop5 sub-samples—see Table 1). Because of their stronger focus on the lending (retail) business, cooperative banks’ stability improves from an increase in diversification of their activities; in contrast, a further move away from retail business in commercial banks, which have already a relatively higher share of other (wholesale) activities, results in decreasing stability (z-scores).Table 8 presents the OECD pooled regressions with the governance indicator constructed by Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2005). As expected, banks in countries with a higher level of institutional development are on average less risky than banks in countries which lack the same governance quality. From a comparison of Tables 7 and 8, the governance indicator does not have a significant impact on the estimated slope coefficients for the commercial and savings bank dummies, suggesting that cooperative banks are not mo re or less sensitive to governance problems than the other types of banks.However, this finding has to be taken with a grain of salt, because we use the overall quality of governance in the country as a proxy for corporate governance in the individual banks, on which there are unfortunately no direct cross-country data. To assess the robustness of our results, we have also estimated models for large and small banks, n addition to the full sample regressions. 22 Table 9 replicates the previous regressions on the OECD, EU12, and Coop5 countries only with large banks, defined as those that have assets larger than US$1 billion.The commercial bank dummy is significantly negative in the In addition, to account for systemic importance, we have also estimated a weighted regression, weighting the different observations by total assets. The results, which were not substantially different from those for large banks in Table 8, are available from the authors upon request. 22 17 pooled OLS estim ations (except the OECD sample). The previous result that a strong cooperative banking sector on average does not weaken the commercial banking sector is strongly supported in the regressions with large banks for all model specifications except the OLS OECD model.Table 10 gives the model findings for small banks (those with assets below US$1 billion). Small commercial banks tend to be riskier than small cooperative banks but there is no substantial evidence that an increase in the cooperative market share has a consistently and significantly negative effect on the smaller commercial banks’ individual risk. As a further sensitivity test, we estimated the models with the robust estimation technique, which assigns lower weights to observations with large residuals, to avoid the impact of outliers (Beck, Cull, and Jerome, 2005).The results in Table 11 support the main conclusion from the previous discussion. Finally, to address the question whether the factors that cause high fra gility are systematically different from the factors that cause medium or low fragility, we adopt quantile regression techniques. Table 12 gives the regression results at the 25th, 50th, and 75th percentiles of the OECD, EU12, and Coop5 countries. 23 The model setup is the same as for the full sample with the same variables included and the same outliers excluded (1st and 99th percentile of the distribution of the z-score).Based on the coefficients of the commercial bank dummy, the gap between the z-scores of commercial and cooperative banks tends to widen with the quantiles in the OECD, EU12, and Coop5 models, which suggests that the distribution of z-scores in cooperatives is much more skewed to the right: if one compares strong cooperative banks and strong commercial banks, the difference in z-scores is much bigger than for weak cooperative banks and weak commercial banks. A similar conclusion is valid also for the comparison of cooperative banks and savings banks, even though th e differences in their z-scores are generally smaller.Upon inspecting the sum of the coefficients of the cooperative share and its interaction with the commercial bank dummy, it appears that an increased presence of cooperative banks per country and year has a negative effect on the weakest commercial banks. In other words, commercial banks that already have low z-scores suffer more from a stronger cooperative sector than commercial banks with higher z-scores. Whereas the previous estimations did not provide any substantial evidence for a negative effect of a higher presence of cooperative 23The 50th percentile gives the median least square estimator which minimizes the median square of residuals rather than the average. In the generalized quantile regression, we estimate an equation describing a quantile other than the median. Specifically, we estimate the first quartile (25th percentile) as well as the 75th percentile. 18 banks on the average commercial bank’s stability, in stead there appears to be some (negative) effect on the weaker commercial banks. In all the regressions, restricting the explanatory variables to only contemporaneous effects does not change the main findings (tables available upon request).We also defined alternative z-scores as ln(1+(z/100)), but this did not affect the main conclusions. IV. CONCLUSIONS AND TOPICS FOR FURTHER RESEARCH The findings in this paper indicate that cooperative banks in advanced economies and emerging markets have higher z-scores than commercial banks and (to a smaller extent) savings banks, suggesting that cooperative banks are more stable. This finding, perhaps somewhat surprising at first, is due to much lower volatility of the cooperative banks’ returns, which more than offsets their relatively lower profitability and capitalization.We suggest that this observed lower variability of returns, and therefore the higher z-scores, may be caused by the fact that cooperative banks in normal times pass on most of their returns to customers, but are able to recoup that surplus in weaker periods. To some extent, this result can also reflect the mutual support mechanisms that many cooperative banks have created. The finding about the higher z-scores in cooperative banks is quite robust with respect to modifications in the measurement of volatility and z-scores.It also remains valid if one distills the â€Å"pure† impact of the cooperative nature of a bank, by using regression analysis and adjusting for differences in bank size, loan to asset ratios, income diversity, and other factors with potential impact on individual bank’s stability. Using the regression analysis, we also find that a higher share of cooperative banks increases stability (measured by z-score) of an average bank in the same banking system. The impacts differ by the groups of banks, however.High presence of cooperative banks appears to weaken commercial banks, in particular those commercial banks that are already weak to start with. This finding is consistent with Goodhart’s (2004) hypothesis that the presence of non-profit-maximizing entities can pull down stability of other financial institutions. This empirical result can be explained by the fact that a higher cooperative bank presence means less space for weak commercial banks in the retail market and therefore their greater reliance on less stable revenue sources such as corporate banking or investment banking.When interpreting the results, one needs to bear in mind some caveats relating to the z-score, such as its reliance on accounting data and its focus on capital and profits rather than, say, liquidity or asset quality. As a robustness test, we have therefore tried to include some possible alternatives to the z-scores, such as ratings. The available data suggest that the ratings of cooperative banks are not substantially worse than those for commercial banks; 19 however, the dominance of observations from one cou ntry (Germany) in the ratings database does not allow for a full-fledged cross-country analysis.Several issues not addressed in this paper could be analyzed in future research. One of them is corporate governance issues. As discussed in Fonteyne (forthcoming) or Cuevas and Fischer (2006), corporate governance issues in cooperatives are often more prominent than in commercial banks. Among these issues is the presence of an owner-less endowment, since members of cooperatives are only invested with the notional value of their shares and have no right to the accumulated capital. Furthermore, there is a collective action problem that might lead to empire-building by management.BankScope and similar databases do not contain institution-specific data on the quality of the corporate governance, but with a more detailed database, perhaps on a smaller sample, it may be possible to analyze this issue. Another issue for further research is the impact of networks on cooperative banks’ sta bility. Cooperative banks can realize important benefits by forming networks, as it allows the pursuit of economies of scale and scope, and the provision of a safety net or mutual support mechanism. However, a more complex structure can also create new challenges for stability.For example, Desrochers and Fischer (2005), in a cross-country survey on the level of integration of cooperatives, note that lateral contracts between cooperatives involve risks that counterparts will behave opportunistically to appropriate the rent generated by the alliance. The analysis based on individual banks’ z-scores, presented in this paper, provides a baseline assessment of systemic stability. To arrive at a more complex assessment, one should look also at losses given default and correlation of losses across defaults (Cihak, 2007).This issue goes beyond the scope of this paper, and is an important topic for further research. Finally, we have treated the share of cooperative banks as an exogeno us variable that impacts the z-scores. When longer time series become available, it might be possible and useful to test whether the share of cooperative banks is in fact endogenous with respect to the z-scores, i. e. , whether this measure of stability affects the share of cooperatives in a system. 20 Table 1. Summary Statistics of Bank-Specific Variables in the Sample, 1994–2004 (In percent, unless indicated otherwise) Assets (Billion USD) Mean Std. Dev.OECD Commercial Cooperative Savings EU12 Commercial Cooperative Savings Coop5 Commercial Cooperative Savings Loans to Assets Cost-Income Ratio Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev. Income Diversity Mean Std. Dev. 3. 78 1. 90 1. 90 32. 52 14. 41 6. 93 0. 57 0. 59 0. 63 0. 21 0. 14 0. 18 70. 27 72. 26 70. 03 44. 47 16. 91 32. 86 0. 33 0. 24 0. 24 0. 25 0. 19 0. 20 8. 94 1. 22 2. 65 43. 06 8. 14 6. 64 0. 43 0. 59 0. 58 0. 28 0. 14 0. 13 70. 10 71. 99 67. 09 42. 23 14. 30 13. 22 0. 39 0. 28 0. 23 0. 49 0. 19 0. 12 18. 06 1. 87 2. 02 79. 75 14. 47 4. 11 0. 50 0. 59 0. 58 0. 28 0. 14 0. 13 71. 79 72. 52 67. 55 43. 43 16. 87 10. 07 0. 34 0. 25 0. 24 0. 4 0. 18 0. 08 Source: Authors' calculation based on BankScope Data. Note: The 1st and 99th percentile of the distribution of the z-score variable is excluded. 21 Table 2. Decomposition of Z-Scores for the Full Sample 1994–2004 Z-score Equity to Assets (percent) ROA (percent) Standard deviation of ROA (% points) All banks Commercial Cooperative Savings Large banks Commercial Cooperative Savings Small banks Commercial Cooperative Savings 50. 0 60. 8 60. 1 12. 13 7. 19 9. 29 0. 94 0. 39 0. 55 0. 59 0. 28 0. 35 29. 6 46. 6 47. 3 7. 06 5. 62 5. 91 0. 69 0. 28 0. 48 0. 71 0. 37 0. 35 46. 5 56. 9 55. 4 11. 21 6. 84 7. 99 0. 90 0. 37 0. 53 0. 65 0. 1 0. 35 Source: Authors’ calculations based on BankScope data. Note: To avoid possible outliers in this sample, the 1st and 99th percentile of the distribution of each variable is excluded. Large (Small) banks are defi ned as having assets larger (smaller) than 1 billion USD. 22 Table 3. Decomposition of Z-Scores for Selected Countries, 1994–2004 Z-score Equity to Assets (percent) ROA (percent) Standard deviation of ROA (percent) Austria Commercial Cooperative France Commercial Cooperative Germany Commercial Cooperative Italy Commercial Cooperative Japan Commercial Cooperative Netherlands Commercial Cooperative UK Commercial Cooperative 28. 70. 9 15. 95 6. 83 1. 01 0. 45 1. 708 0. 122 44. 4 82. 2 13. 31 5. 44 1. 07 0. 29 0. 471 0. 067 25. 8 33. 5 4. 47 5. 43 -0. 16 -0. 04 0. 949 1. 001 30. 7 40. 3 11. 44 12. 89 0. 43 0. 88 1. 246 0. 465 37. 3 78. 8 12. 05 5. 08 0. 48 0. 28 1. 197 0. 124 17. 8 42. 1 10. 69 6. 64 0. 39 0. 58 2. 088 0. 223 33. 8 34. 3 11. 20 6. 02 0. 70 0. 39 0. 846 0. 407 Source: Authors’ calculations based on BankScope data. Note: To avoid possible outliers in this sample, the 1st and 99th percentile of the distribution of each variable is excluded. All selected count ries have a market share of cooperative banks higher than 5%. 23Table 4. Sensitivity of the Z-score Decomposition Bank type Commercial Cooperative Savings Return on assets Downward volatility (percentage points) Upward volatility (percentage points) Z-scores Downward volatility (percentage points) Upward volatility (percentage points) Equity to assets Downward volatility (percentage points) Upward volatility (percentage points) -0. 46 0. 38 -0. 19 0. 20 -0. 21 0. 21 -3. 79 3. 99 -3. 47 3. 85 -3. 78 4. 12 -1. 53 1. 69 -0. 53 0. 58 -0. 78 0. 81 Distribution of Z-scores (% of observations in banks of the same type) Less than 0 0. 37 0 to 10 13. 65 10 to 20 14. 74 20 to 30 13. 2 More than 30 57. 52 0. 62 9. 20 10. 72 13. 04 66. 42 0. 13 6. 38 9. 85 14. 80 68. 84 Source: Authors' calculation based on BankScope data. Note: To eliminate outliers, the 1st and and 99th percentiles of the distribution of the downward (upward) volatility variables were excluded. 24 Table 5. Fitch's Long-Term R atings of the Banks in Sample All Banks No. Percent 2 0. 17 16 1. 36 26 2. 21 72 6. 11 781 66. 30 77 6. 54 64 5. 43 40 3. 40 35 2. 97 29 2. 46 10 0. 85 2 0. 17 15 1. 27 4 0. 34 3 0. 25 2 0. 17 1,178 100. 00 Commercial No. Percent 2 0. 54 14 3. 75 23 6. 17 66 17. 69 53 14. 21 54 14. 48 39 10. 46 38 10. 9 28 7. 51 24 6. 43 7 1. 88 2 0. 54 14 3. 75 4 1. 07 3 0. 80 2 0. 54 373 100 Cooperative No. Percent 0 0. 00 1 0. 15 2 0. 29 2 0. 29 664 96. 37 9 1. 31 7 1. 02 0 0. 00 2 0. 29 1 0. 15 0 0. 00 0 0. 00 1 0. 15 0 0. 00 0 0. 00 0 0. 00 689 100. 00 AAA AA+ AA AAA+ A ABBB+ BBB BBBBB+ BB BBB+ B BTotal Note: All 637 cooperative banks in Germany have a Fitch rating of A+. 25 Table 6. Correlation Coefficients between the Z-Score and Selected Key Variables, 1994–2004 Commercial Bank Dummy Cooperative Bank Dummy Savings Bank Dummy Share Coop Share Coop* Commercial Full Sample OECD -0. 060*** 0. 026*** 0. 051*** -0. 041*** -0. 38*** Large Banks OECD -0. 225*** 0. 115*** 0. 147*** 0. 100*** - 0. 168*** Small Banks OECD -0. 047*** 0. 013*** 0. 050*** -0. 034*** -0. 105*** EU12 -0. 244*** 0. 178*** 0. 041*** 0. 128*** -0. 184*** Coop5 -0. 221*** 0. 137*** 0. 066*** 0. 068*** -0. 195*** Commercial Bank Dummy Cooperative Bank Dummy Savings Bank Dummy Share Coop Share Coop* Commercial EU12 -0. 340*** 0. 115*** 0. 236*** 0. 130*** -0. 241*** Coop5 -0. 288*** 0. 091*** 0. 208*** 0. 085*** -0. 245*** Commercial Bank Dummy Cooperative Bank Dummy Savings Bank Dummy Share Coop Share Coop* Commercial EU12 -0. 179*** 0. 160*** -0. 008*** 0. 098*** -0. 144***Coop5 -0. 155*** 0. 119*** 0. 001 0. 052*** -0. 141*** Note: * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 26 Table 7. Regression Results (Full Sample) OECD (1) Assets (-1) Loans/ Assets (-1) Cost-Income Ratio (-1) Income Diversity (-1) Income Diversity* Cooperative Bank Dummy (-1) Herfindahl Index (-1) Commercial Bank Dummy Savings Bank Dummy Share of Cooperatives (-1) Share of Cooperatives * Commercial Bank Dummy (-1) GDP Growth (-1) Inflation (-1) Exchange Rate Appreciation (-1) Real Long-Term Interest Rate (-1) Constant Observations R-squared Clustered by Banks Type -0. 026 (0. 000)*** -13. 123 (0. 00)*** -0. 185 (0. 000)*** -19. 299 (0. 000)*** 23. 107 (0. 000)*** -0. 005 (0. 000)*** -4. 79 (0. 029)** -2. 547 (0. 196) -0. 094 (0. 324) -0. 386 (0. 000)*** -0. 246 (0. 037)** 0. 44 (0. 006)*** 0. 043 (0. 009)*** -0. 398 (0. 004)*** 39. 898 (0. 000)*** 78,298 0. 103 14,025 OLS (2) -0. 013 (0. 023)** -3. 225 (0. 000)*** -0. 001 (0. 572) -1. 132 (0. 004)*** 3. 67 (0. 000)*** 0. 001 (0. 002)*** (3) -0. 027 (0. 073)* 3. 802 (0. 318) -0. 044 (0. 038)** -3. 4 (0. 155) 6. 877 (0. 184) -0. 005 (0. 005)*** -22. 685 (0. 000)*** -7. 437 (0. 003)*** 0. 278 (0. 033)** -0. 027 (0. 866) -0. 081 (0. 786) -1. 901 (0. 000)*** 0. 34 (0. 096)* 0. 597 (0. 145) 55. 966 (0. 000)*** 22,665 0. 112 3,239 OLS EU12 (4) -0. 043 (0. 000)*** -1. 996 (0. 347) -0. 009 (0. 076)* -0. 742 (0. 184) 4. 534 (0. 000)*** -0. 0 004 (0. 537) (5) -0. 019 (0. 001)*** 3. 461 (0. 349) -0. 078 (0. 000)*** -4. 12 (0. 107) 13. 418 (0. 004)*** 0. 001 (0. 643) -17. 143 (0. 000)*** -4. 314 (0. 080)* 0. 086 (0. 557) -0. 003 (0. 989) 1. 002 (0. 000)*** 0. 091 (0. 789) 0. 061 (0. 015)** -0. 006 (0. 987) 22. 558 (0. 000)*** 25,241 0. 106 3,723 OLS Coop5 (6) -0. 015 (0. 028)** 0. 882 (0. 705) -0. 008 (0. 032)** -0. 858 (0. 077)* 2. 585 (0. 001)*** 0. 005 (0. 000)*** 0. 114 (0. 01)*** 0. 019 (0. 699) -0. 14 (0. 001)*** 0. 133 (0. 009)*** 0. 068 (0. 000)*** 0. 184 (0. 000)*** 46. 652 (0. 000)*** 78,298 0. 058 14,025 FE 0. 127 (0. 007)*** -0. 101 (0. 093)* 0. 012 (0. 924) -0. 427 (

Friday, August 30, 2019

Stefan’s Diaries: Origins Chapter 15

As soon as twilight fell, I sneaked down the stairs, opened the back door, and tiptoed out onto the grass, already wet with dew. I was extra cautious, since there were torches surrounding the estate and I knew Father would be displeased that I was venturing out after dark. But the carriage house was only a stone's throw from the house itself–about twenty paces from the porch. I stole across the yard, staying in the shadows, feeling my heart pound against my rib cage. I wasn't concerned about animal attacks or creatures of the night. I was more concerned that I'd be found by Alfred or, worse, Father. But the notion of not being able to see Katherine that night made me feel hysterical. Once again, a heavy fog blanketed the ground and rose to the sky, an odd reversal of nature that most likely was due to the changing of the seasons. I shivered and made sure to look away from the willow tree as I ran to the bridle path and up the porch steps of the carriage house. I paused at the whitewashed door. The curtains on the windowpanes were pulled shut, and I couldn't see any candlelight seeping under the windows. For a second, I feared I had come too late. What if Katherine and Emily had retired to bed? Still, I rapped my knuckles sharply against the wooden door frame. The door creaked open and a hand grabbed my wrist. â€Å"Come in!† I heard a rough whisper as I was swept into the house. Behind me, I heard the click of the lock and realized I was standing face-to- face with Emily. â€Å"Sir,† Emily said, smiling as she curtseyed. She was dressed in a simple navy gown, and her hair fell in dark waves around her shoulders. â€Å"Good evening,† I said, bowing gently. I glanced around the little house, allowing my eyes to adjust to the dim light. A red lantern glowed on the rough-hewn table in the living room, casting shadows against the wooden beams of the ceiling. The carriage house had been in a state of disrepair for years, ever since Mother had died and her relatives had stopped visiting. But now that it was inhabited, there was a warmth to the rooms that was absent in the main house. â€Å"What can I do for you, sir?† Emily asked, her dark eyes unblinking. â€Å"Um †¦ I'm here to see Katherine,† I stammered, suddenly embarrassed. What would Emily think of her mistress? Of course, maids are meant to be discreet, but I knew how servants talked, and I certainly didn't want Katherine's virtue to be compromised if Emily was the type to engage in idle servant gossip. â€Å"Katherine has been expecting you,† Emily said, a glint of mischief in her dark eyes. She took the lantern from the table and led me up the wooden stairs, stopping at the white door at the end of the hallway. I squinted. When Damon and I were little, we'd always been vaguely afraid of the upstairs of the carriage house. Maybe it was because the servants had said it was haunted, maybe because every floorboard had creaked, but something about the space had stopped us from staying very long. Now that Katherine was here, though, there was nowhere else I'd rather be. Emily turned toward me, her knuckles on the door. She rapped three times. Then she swung the door open. I walked cautiously into the room, the floorboards creaking as Emily disappeared down the hallway. The room itself was furnished simply: a cast-iron bed covered by a simple green quilt, an armoire in one corner, a washbasin in another, and a gilt-plated, freestanding mirror in a third corner. Katherine sat on her bed, facing the window, her back to me. Her legs were tucked under her short white nightgown and her long curls were loose over her shoulders. I stood there, watching Katherine, then finally coughed. She turned around, an expression of amusement in her dark, cat-like eyes. â€Å"I'm here,† I said, shifting from one booted foot to the other. â€Å"So I see.† Katherine grinned. â€Å"I watched you walk here. Were you frightened to be out after dark?† â€Å"No!† I said defensively, embarrassed she'd seen me dart from tree to tree like an overcautious squirrel. Katherine arched a dark eyebrow and held her arms out toward me. â€Å"Y need to stop worrying. ou Come here. I'll help you take your mind off things,† she said, raising her eyebrow. I walked toward her as if in a dream, knelt on the bed, and hugged her tightly. As soon as I felt her body in my hands, I relaxed. Just feeling her was a reminder that she was real, that tonight was real, that nothing else mattered–not Father, not Rosalyn, not the spirits the townspeople were convinced roamed outside in the dark. All that mattered was that my arms were around my love. Her hand worked its way down my shoulders, and I imagined us walking into the Founders Ball together. As her hand stopped at my shoulder blade and I felt her fingernails dig through the thin cotton of my shirt, I had a split- second image of us, ten years from now, with plenty of children who'd fill the estate with sounds of laughter. I wanted this life to be mine, now and forever. I moaned with desire and leaned in, allowing my lips to brush hers, first slowly, as we'd do in front of everyone when we announced our love at our wedding, and then harder and more urgently, allowing my lips to travel from her mouth to her neck, inching toward her snow-white bosom. She grabbed my chin and pulled my face to hers and kissed me hard. I reciprocated. It was as if I were a starving man who'd finally found sustenance in her mouth. We kissed, and I closed my eyes and forgot about the future. All of a sudden, I felt a sharp pain on my neck, as if I were being stabbed. I called out, but Katherine was still kissing me. But no, not kissing, biting, sucking the blood from beneath my skin. My eyes flew open, and I saw Katherine's eyes, wild and bloodshot, her face ghostly white in the moonlight. I wrenched my head back, but the pain was unrelenting, and I couldn't scream, couldn't fight, could only see the full moon out the window, and could only feel the blood leaving my body, and desire and heat and anger and terror all welling up inside me. If this was what death felt like, then I wanted it. I wanted it, and that was when I flung my arms around Katherine, giving myself to her. Then everything faded to black.

Thursday, August 29, 2019

Annotated Soap Note Hair Loss

Relevant history positive for family history of hair thinning on both sides. Relevant history negative for anemia, hyperthyroidism, hypothyroidism, rheumatoid arthritis, vitiligo or ulcerative colitis. The patient is not currently pregnant. Associated symptoms include intentional weight loss of 50 lbs over 10 months. Pertinent negatives include anxiety, depression, dry scalp, fever, heat intolerance, itchy scalp, rash, scalp kerion, scalp tenderness or skin sores. Noticed hair thinning for about 5 months. No bald spots, lesions on scalp or skin. Estimates she has lost 25% of hair thickness. Chronic Problems Past Medical/Surgical History 1996 (R) Shoulder arthroscopy Obstetric History G1P1. Not pregnant. Family History Disease Detail Family Member Age Cardiomyopathy Father67 (cause of death) Cancer -lungMother59 (cause of death) HypothyroidMother Social History Employment: Property Management, no exposure to chemicals. Marital Status / Family: Currently single, previously divorced once, not in relationship since divorce. Has an 11-year-old daughter. Tobacco: Never smoked. Alcohol: Occasional beer. Caffeine: coffee- 3 cups a day. Lifestyle: Moderate activity level. Exercises 3-4 days per week and takes care of horses daily. Medications (Active) Medication Name Mirena IUD, placed in 2012. Aleve as needed, taking several times a week over winter. Allergies: NKANo Known Drug Allergies Review of Systems Constitutional: Positive for: Weight loss. Has been following a very low carb diet and has lost 50 lbs. since July. No protein, nonstarchy vegetable or calorie restriction. Negative: fever and night sweats. Respiratory: Negative: cough, dyspnea. Cardiovascular: Negative: chest pain and irregular heartbeat/palpitations. Gastrointestinal: Negative: abdominal pain, constipation and diarrhea. Genitourinary: The patient is pre-menopausal. No menses with IUD. Negative: dysuria. Metabolic/Endocrine: Positive for hair loss, see HPI. Weight loss from diet and lifestyle changes. Negative: heat or cold intolerance. Neuro/Psychiatric: Negative: anxiety and depression. Negative: extremity weakness, headache and numbness or weakness in extremities. Dermatologic: No hirsutism or signs of virilization, nail changes, rash, or skin sores. Scalp without pruritus, burning, or lesions. No new hair products. Shampoos daily. No chemical hair treatments. No hair loss on other parts of body. Hair lost has roots, no hair breakage. Does not put hair into braids or ponytails on regular basis. See Chief Complaint and HPI. Musculoskeletal: Negative: joint pain and joint swelling. Hematology: Negative: easy bleeding, bruising or history of anemia. Vital Signs. Height: 5’8† Weight: 237 BMI: 36 Blood Pressure: 130/75 Pulse: 80 Physical Exam Constitutional: Well developed, no distress. Eyes: PERRLA, no injection, bilaterally. Neck / Thyroid: Symmetric, trachea midline and mobile. No thyromegaly or thyroid nodules. Lymphatic: No cervical or supraclavicular adenopathy. Respiratory: Chest symmetric. Lungs clear to auscultation. Respiratory effort is normal. Cardiovascular: Regular rate and rhythm with normal S1, S2. No murmur or rub. Abdomen: Nontender. No masses or organomegaly, exam limited by obesity. No bruits. Integumentary: No skin lesions present. Nails appear normal. No scalp erythema, scales, papules, pustules, erosions, or excoriations. Hair loss most noticeable in temporal region, equal bilaterally. Extremities: No edema is present. Psychiatric: Oriented to time, place, person, and situation. Has appropriate mood and affect. Assessment: Telogen effluvium (704. 02) Hair loss is classified into 3 classifications, cicatricial alopecia (inflammatory), nonscarring alopecia and inherited and acquired structural hair disorders. In evaluating hair loss it is important to assess duration and rate, location and pattern, extent of loss, associated symptoms, hair care practices, and differentiation of hair shedding from breakage. Medical and family history, diet, and medications need to be assessed (Shapiro, Otberg, Hordinsky, 2013). Telogen effluvium is diffuse hair loss that is reversible caused by a significant stressor such as significant weight loss, pregnancy, major illness or surgery (Goldstein Goldstein, 2012). As the patient has lost 50 pound in 10 months, this is the most likely cause of her diffuse hair loss. She will stop her very low carbohydrate diet for a more moderate, varied diet. If the hair loss continues she will need further evaluation. Differential diagnosis 1. Endocrine related hair loss: Hair loss may be caused by several endocrine disorders, presentation is typically with non-scarring alopecia that is diffuse (Olszewska, Warszawik, Rakowska, Slowinska, Rudnicka, 2011). †¢Hypopituitarism, not assessed, needs serum cortisol (Synder, 2012), will order if symptoms continue. †¢Hypothyroidism, ruled out, TSH normal. †¢Hyperthyroidism, ruled out, TSH normal. †¢Diabetes mellitus, ruled out, fasting glucose normal. †¢Growth hormone deficiency, unlikely obese adult of greater than normal height. †¢Hyperprolactinaemia, ruled out, prolactin normal. †¢Polycystic ovary syndrome, unlikely. No hirsutism, virilization, acne, infertility, or history of menstrual irregularities (prior to amenorrhea from IUD) (Barbieri Ehrmann, 2012). †¢Congenital adrenal hyperplasia (late onset), unlikely, no hirsutism or menstrual irregularities (Merke, 2013). 2. Alopecia areata : Diagnosis is unlikely, as alopecia areata is considered an autoimmune disease, with significant associations with vitiligo, lupus erythematosus, psoriasis, atopic dermatitis, autoimmune thyroid disease, and allergic rhinitis. ESR was normal, and this patient has no symptoms of inflammation due to autoimmune disease (Chu et al. 2011). 3. Drug related alopecia areata : NSAIDs have been associated with hair loss (WebMD, 2012). Patient reports taking regular naproxen, for the last few months due to muscle aches from exercise and taking care of her horses in the winter. However, this was not until after hair loss started, so may be a contributing factor but not direct cause. Recommended to stop all NSAIDs until problem is corrected. 4. Excess vitamin A: Vitamin A is toxic above daily intakes of greater than 25,000 IU for more than 6 years or more than 100,000 IU for at least 6 months (Penniston Tanumihardjo, 2006). This patient’s largest source of vitamin a has been leafy greens almost daily. Two cups of spinach has under 20,000 IU of vitamin A. She is not taking a vitamin a supplement. Therefore vitamin a toxicity is unlikely. 5. Syphilitic alopecia: Unlikely as patient tested negative for syphilis during her pregnancy, and has remained celibate since her divorce, several years later. Syphilitic alopecia occurs in only 4% of patients with syphilis (Hernadez-Bel, Unamuno, Sanchez-Carazo, Febrer, Alegre, 2012). 6. Nutritional deficiencies: Although this is a likely cause, it difficult to determine if hair loss is from significant weight loss or nutritional deficiencies from a very low carbohydrate diet lasting 10 months. Deprivation of several components, such as proteins, minerals, fatty acids, and vitamins, can lead to structural deformities, changes in pigmentation, or hair loss. One example, Acrodermatitis enteropathica, is caused by zinc deficiency (Finner, 2013). As the patient was eating a high protein, moderate fat, very low carbohydrate (vegetables only), a zinc deficiency is unlikely as it is closely related to protein intake. She also ate a large amount of vegetables daily. A vitamin or mineral closely linked to grains only would be a likely cause. Plan Telogen effluvium (704. 02) 1. FERRITIN HGB ESR TSH PROLACTIN all normal. 2. The loss of 50 pounds is overall very beneficial and will improve your health. However, this can cause hair loss, which is temporary and reversible. Regrowth should occur over 3 to 4 months. 3. I recommend a more moderate low carbohydrate diet and slower weight loss to lower the stress on your body. 4. As NSAIDs, such as Aleve, can cause hair loss, I would also advise to avoid them until the symptoms have resolved. 5. Return for further evaluation if hair loss does not resolve in three to four months. If no improvement or if your symptoms progress, follow up with a dermatologist. ? References Barbieri, R. L. , Ehrmann, D. A. (2012). Clinical manifestations of polycystic ovary syndrome in adults. Retrieved from http://www. uptodate. com/contents/clinical-manifestations-of-polycystic-ovary-syndrome-in-adults? source=search_resultsearch=pcosselectedTitle=4%7E

Wednesday, August 28, 2019

Recovery for Athletes Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 250 words

Recovery for Athletes - Essay Example These are all necessary for them to maximize performance. The chosen article entitled â€Å"Using Recovery Modalities between Training Sessions in Elite Athletes Does it Help? Authored by Anthony Barnett, highlights the wide range, evidenced-based recovery modalities for enhancing between-training session recovery among elite athletes and presented the efficacy for each recovery modality to reduce the severity and period of exercise-induced muscle injury, as well as, delayed onset muscle soreness (DOMS). The said modalities are as follows: First is the massage, which is used in the training of athletes and have been known to decrease oedema and pain; Second is the active recovery, a technique based on post exercises to remove lactate; Third is the cryotherapy is used actively to treat acute traumatic injury and considered appropriate as a recovery modality of post-train- modality following training and competition; Next is the contrast temperature that utilizes water immersion alter nating the warm-to-hot and cold water; Another is the hyperbaric oxygen therapy, which involves the whole-body exposure to pressure >1 atmosphere while breathing the 100% oxygen.

Tuesday, August 27, 2019

BudgetExpenditure analysis Assignment Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 500 words

BudgetExpenditure analysis - Assignment Example While this may be possible in many organizations, in Monroe county Red Cross, it might not be fully possible especially because of the nature of management of the organization. To start with, most of its incomes are from donations and other incomes of the same nature. It may be difficult to establish exactly what amount is spent in preparation activities. Moreover, the organization is more of a charitable organization concerned with offering services and not profit maximization. All in all, expenditure analysis must be carried out more so to convince well wishers and donors that their funds are being spent in a good manner. In Monroe county Red Cross, the process often takes four main stages which are dependent on one another. For a comprehensive summary of expenditure analysis, it ought to start at the budget preparation stage. Here all the relevant factors are taken into consideration. It is in the process of budgeting that speculations of spending are made. Despite the fact that in many instances these speculations are not accurate, they give the management a rough idea of the likely range of expenditures. Though it is often overlooked by many institutions including the Monroe county Red Cross, expenditure analysis ought to start at this point. The items in the budget ought to be reviewed and confirmations made on whether or not they are likely to cost as much as stipulated in the budget. After the process of budget preparation, approval needs to be done. In many instances and many organizations, this step is the where the budget expenditures are analysed. The purpose of this step is to eradicate alien expenditures that may be fixed to acquire money in unscrupulous ways. Depending on the views of the management and the urgency of the expenditures, they may be approved or rejected in the budget. This is still some form of expenditure analysis. After the approval

Monday, August 26, 2019

Medical Marijuana Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 750 words - 1

Medical Marijuana - Essay Example According to the essay the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) in the United States has approved the use of chemicals extracted from marijuana known as cannabinoids. The endorsement was made after scientific studies conducted on chemical components of the drug. Further, pharmaceutical drugs have been developed using marijuana chemicals for therapeutic purposes at the same time removing chemicals that have been causing side effects and highness.This study declares that medical marijuana laws MML have was passed in states like Maryland to remove penalties imposed on users of marijuana whenever they are got in possession of or using marijuana. According to medical marijuana laws, doctors are expected to provide approval to patients regarding the use of marijuana for medical benefits. The approval given to patients will render them immune to any prosecution by states when they are got in possession or using marijuana.  Marijuana use has been associated with increased motor vehicle accid ents and increasing burden on healthcare. Longer use of the drug has contributed to brain damage, cognitive impairment and respiratory damage when smoked. Other heath related risks associated with the use of marijuana includes bronchitis, lung cancer, heart attack and wheezing.  Use of marijuana for a long time is likely to cause severe implications stated above. Those against the use of marijuana for medical purpose explain that marijuana has two chemical components  that are harmful to human.

Sunday, August 25, 2019

THE IMPORTANT CONTRIBUTIONS OF ECONOMIC Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 750 words

THE IMPORTANT CONTRIBUTIONS OF ECONOMIC - Essay Example It emphasized that foreign goods should only be imported if there is an indispensable need and that too for exchange of domestic products instead of gold and silver. The mercantilist thought opposed free trade with other countries and empires believing that it was fruitless and beneficial to one side only. This paper aims to investigate the important contributions made by the critics of mercantilism which led to the development of classical economic thought (The economist, ). The mercantilist policies, where successful, produced an oversupply of wealth eventually leading to severe inflation. Sooner, protests against government regulations were voiced due to fiscal difficulties. In the late 17th and 18th centuries in France, economists developed physiocracy (government of nature) which advocated agricultural practices, land development and stressed on higher pricing of agricultural commodities. Pierre le Pesant de Boisguilbert opposed the prohibition of export of grain which was ruining the neglected agriculture sector. Fracois Quesnay in his work ‘Tableau Economique’ also opposed trade and industry as sources of wealth arguing that real economy mover was productivity in agricultural and diffusion of its surpluses in the system. Marshal Vauban asserted that working class were the main pillars of social welfare and should be protected. Among other notable contributors were Richard Cantillon, Marquis d’Argenson and Vincent de Gournay who advocated free trade and is believed to have originated the physiocratic slogan ‘laissez faire, laissez passer’ meaning ‘let it be, let it pass’. John Law in his ‘credit theory of money’ proposed that since silver and gold fluctuate, land would be the most stable measure of value. He proposed the use of mortgage-notes for mobilization and paper money for domestic circulation upon security of land. Similarly in Britain, William Petty, John Locke, Dudely North, David Hume and others strongly criticized

Somalia Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 2000 words

Somalia - Essay Example In our present age, Somalia has always been the epitome of poverty. Pictures of toothpick-thin Somali children have flooded the magazines all over the world, with drooping eyes seemingly begging for our help. Until now, their state conditions had barely changed. Almost 15 years after Somalia fell apart in 1991 in spate of clan-based rebellions against the genocidal, 22-year dictatorship of President Mohammed Siad Barre, the fear and the loathing in this country still exists. Since 1991, there have been fourteen efforts at national reconciliation; to date, none has been successful. Various groupings of Somali factions have sought to control the national territory (or portions thereof) and have fought small wars with one another. Dahir Riyale Kahin was elected President of the self-declared "Republic of Somaliland," which is made up of the former northwest provinces of the Somali republic, in presidential elections deemed free and fair by international observers in May 2003. In 1998, t he area of Puntland in the northeast declared itself autonomous (although not independent) as the "State of Puntland" with its capital at Garowe. Puntland declared it would remain autonomous until a federated Somalia state was established (US Department of State, 2005). As we all know, the terrible famine of 1993 in the south was entirely induced by civil war. A US- and UN-led humanitarian intervention failed to understand Somali complexities, was humiliated, and when it left in 1995 had only instigated more conflicts to arise.

Saturday, August 24, 2019

What is buddhism Is it a philosophy or a religion Essay

What is buddhism Is it a philosophy or a religion - Essay Example s study on whether Buddhism is a religion or a philosophy putting into consideration some of the theories applied, the history of Buddhism, Buddha – its religious figure and its literature. The paper will not lie on one side of the thesis question i.e. whether Buddhism is a religion or philosophy, but it will evaluate both notions mostly according to Olson’s conclusions on the matter. In the book ‘The Different Path of Buddhism’ Olson starts by first making a quick account of the early Buddhist tradition of how an old woman, friends with the monks, died and the monks were inconsolable. After which Buddha told them the story about kaka Jataka, the crow and the day when one of the crows got very drunk and was swept out to the sea and drowned; he used the story for symbolism where the sea was a metaphor for the suffering associated with life and the crows represented the human beings (Olson 1). Olson says that during this time of Buddhism, Buddha was considered an common man of flesh and blood, and an exceptional fascinating teacher; not a manifestation of divine being. He is best known as an educator, philosopher, and founder of a major world religion; significantly, he is not like other religious figures that were considered to be holy beings like Jesus (Christianity) or Muhammad (Islam). However, like these other religious figures, Buddha gathered a small group of followers who were attracted to his charisma and teaching, but insisted on the creation of a monastic community that shaped those who joined it and influenced Indian culture, and the laity who were necessary for its support (Olson 3). Before the formation of Buddhism, there were only two religious movements in India; the Brahmins – Brahmanical culture and the holy wanderers – Indian culture; notably, the Buddhists supported the holy wanderers and rejected certain ways of the Brahmanical religion but accepted others (Olson 5). Buddhism was later formed from an incorporation of some features

Friday, August 23, 2019

Should Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) be considered in the Research Paper

Should Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) be considered in the rating of Wall Street companies - Research Paper Example This poses the question whether CSR should be considered in rating of Wall Street companies. In this paper, CSR is discussed in cases for and against inclusion in Wall Street company ratings. Approaches to CSR, research and trends are also examined. The author argues that CSR is important and should be considered side by side the companies’ ratings so that stakeholders get a clearer picture about the companies’ operations in the society they work with. The author proposes a simple, qualitative rating scale as a starting point for something as universal as CSR for inclusion in rating Wall Street Companies. Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) is an ethical belief and practice that companies, just like individuals, are responsibilities as good stewards of the society in which they do business with (Wood, 1991). Corporations have an obligation to act in ways that will benefit or sustain society and that their responsibility is not lim ited to their profit. In the last decade, we have seen movements gather momentum requesting for more corporate social responsibilities in ethical practices, for the environment, the working conditions of employees, for the local communities, and towards all stakeholders from suppliers to post-consumption of products. CSR is soon to be integrated with the human resources, business development, operations, and relations (Barnea and Rubin, 2010). This paper will examine the two companies rated by Wall Street: Goldman Sachs and British Petroleum (BP), which very recently have been involved in practices that did not do well to the society in which they do business with. An attempt will be made to see if CSR should be considered in their ratings. In the year 2010, each of the three major credit rating agencies - Moody’s Investor Services, Standard & Poor's and Fitch Ratings - rated both of these companies mainly on their credit worthiness. In the same year, Fortune Magazine also na med them as two of the world’s most admired companies. The question then is whether these companies should be rated solely on scales that show their credit-worthiness or should these ratings also include a dimension that will show how well a company performing in the society in general. British Petroleum (BP) In April 2010, an explosion occurred on BP's oil rig in the Gulf of Mexico. The Coast Guard reported that 11 people were killed, 17 other others injured and about 4.9 million barrels of oil released to the Gulf of Mexico affecting Louisiana, Alabama, Mississippi and Florida. The oil spill caused extensive environmental damage to the sea and wildlife creatures in the Gulf of Mexico. It also damaged the fishing and tourism industries. The US Government held BP accountable for the damages. BP officials committed to shoulder all cleanup costs and other damages. In addition, the company is also being investigated for alleged unsafe practices which caused the occurrence on the rig leading to the explosion. An internal probe made BP admit to mistakes that led to the oil spill in the Gulf of Mexico. In 2010, Moody’s rated BP’s senior unsecured ratings as an Aa2 from Aa1. Fitch Ratings rated BP’s long-term issuer default rating and senior unsecured rating as an AA from AA+. Reuters also reported in June 2010 that Standard and

Thursday, August 22, 2019

Columbus Day Essay Example for Free

Columbus Day Essay When asked should Columbus Day be celebrated? The answer we get is yes because we have a holiday on Monday of the second week of October. Columbus Day is the celebration of the day Christopher Columbus apparently discovered America. If I was asked that question I would say most definitely we shouldn’t celebrate Columbus Day. First, he brought disease that spread around the Americas killing 9off the Native Americans. Second, most people think that by celebrating Columbus Day we are celebrating the discovery of America, which is not true. Third, he destroyed Native Americans and their culture. Firstly, he brought a boat load of disease that spread around the Americas killing off the Native Americans. When Christopher Columbus came to America he brought many diseases that Native Americans weren’t immune to. Some of the diseases he brought were measles, mumps, smallpox, and many more. Smallpox was one of the most know disease he brought to America. The Native Americans had never been exposed to these types of diseases and millions of them died from it. The diseases would kill the entire families and villages and cause of that Native American tribes and cultures were damaged. By celebrating Columbus Day we are celebrating the damage he produced to Native Americans. Secondly, most people think that by celebrating Columbus Day we are celebrating the discovery of America, which is not true. How can America be ever discovered by him if there were people living there? America was already exiting and you can’t discover something that already exists. Christopher Columbus did not find North American on purpose and he was not the first to find it either. Leif Ericsson of the Viking found North America first. So technically Christopher Columbus didn’t discover America so why should we have a day just for him? It just doesn’t make sense to have a holiday for someone but there is no really reason behind it. Thirdly, he destroyed Native Americans and their culture. Christopher Columbus was an uncaring and a harsh person. He mistreated Native Americans when they tried to be welcoming to him and his crew. He killed many Native Americans and slaves, the killing led to culture and tribes damaging. The only thing he was after for were Gold and Slaves. He took so much from the helpless Native Americans and was selfish and heartless. He neglected them in every nasty way possible and gave them cruel and unusual punishments. Why should we celebrate a day for a person that has mistreated our people? That like saying you have used me many times but I will still go back to you. We shouldn’t celebrate a day for a person that was as careless, and heartless as him. In conclusion, in America every year we celebrate a day called Columbus Day. Many people believe we celebrate Columbus Day because he discovered America. It’s not possible for him to discover America if there were people living there already. If you look deep into what worthy and cruel things Columbus had done for us, most of them will be cruel things. I don’t think we would want to have a national holiday for the person who has done so much cruel things to us. Firstly, he brought lots of disease that spread around the Americas killing off the Native Americans. Secondly, most people think that by celebrating Columbus Day we are celebrating the discovery of America, which is not true. Thirdly, he destroyed Native Americans and their culture. In my opinion we should not Celebrate Columbus Day.

Wednesday, August 21, 2019

Hazardous Chemical Materials

Hazardous Chemical Materials Hazardous chemical defined as the whispering killers. Chemical materials evade our life. It is the substances of harmful on humans, animals and all things on the ground. Chemical Hazardous cause big harm on our heath. Chemical materials effects badly on our life. Many people death in resulting to these chemical materials. People must fare away about using chemical materials because of its damages and hazardous. Injection, breathing, swallowing, skin and ingestion are the way to enter the chemical materials in our body. We should dealing carefully about the chemical materials to be safe our life and safe our generation. There are many ways to prevent the damages of chemical materials. Everything around us contain chemical materials. We should keep aware of using every things in our daily life. Hazardous chemical material is the substance that remain in the environment for many times, and not leave the environment or dissolve easily. When chemical materials produced in the environment, They stay in the ground, water, and all place in the environment for long times. When we spray The pesticides for killing the insects towards the insects, the material remain in the room for many times so the material damage us and our children. Hazardous chemical materials have many number of toxic effects which effects badly on all who live in the environment whether humans, animals, plants and so on. These chemical material damages people by many killing diseases like cancer, the damaging of the nervous system, disrupting in all part in human body. When people spray chemical materials on plants to grow faster, they damages the plants. After growing the plants, people go to eat these plants which grow from   chemical material and then they are caused by many diseases which can kill or hur t them. There are many negative effects of using the chemical materials. It has not any positive effects from using it. Chemical materials exit into the treatment and drugs. People think that drugs recover them. This belief is wrong. Drugs which made of chemical materials damage the human health so the wisdom which states that the prevention is better than cure, is very fact and correct. The chemical material is known as any material damage our health. Chemical materials existed in our life as the existing of water and plants. Our foods, clothes, vegetables and water made of chemical materials. Many people thought that chemical materials doesnt damage our life but this belief is wrong. In fact all chemical materials are harmful on us and on our environment. Many of chemical material may be poison or harm on the environment. We use chemical material on our daily life in fact. Chemical materials entered in all industries such as the pesticides material when we kill the insects. We kill the insects and the pesticides kill us as a killer silence. Drugs also made from the chemical materials. We take the drugs to recovery then these drugs effects badly our life in the long term. In addition, the environment exposure humans, animals and plants to many hazards such as the radiation, bacteria and viruses. Chemical materials founded in all place. Chemical material existed in a ir, water, drugs, insecticide and even in cosmetics. Chemical materials have catastrophic effects such as explosion and flammability and others. The chemical industries lead to the harm all environment. There are many ways should follow to prevent the hazardous of chemical materials. Recycling is one of the most process to prevent the damages of chemical materials. Returning items help to damage these chemical material and we can benefit from it instead of damaging us. The second way to prevent chemical material is the following of the duties that you have been learned and trained. Doing jobs to fullest extent possible help to us to develop our thinking about giving solution to use materials in good ways. Keeping the place, you work or stay also help to reduce the damaging of chemical hazards. When we clean everything that around us, the chemical materials which exiting in these things can be minimized the risks. Reading the consequences of using the material chemical before using it, reducing the damaging of catching diseases. Safety data of how using any material help us more to prevent the diseases which came from chemical materials. Eating or drinking during catching material ch emical, is very serious on our heath. When people use cosmetic or lenses and dont wash their hand carefully, people already catch diseases because these cosmetic contain of chemical materials. There are many ways also to prevent chemical materials. Minimizing the activities and processes which came from emission, helping to prevent catching diseases on our heath as possible. Moving away and departure from using substances which doesnt benefit us helping us to minimize the spreading of chemical materials. There are many ways to catch diseases from the using of the chemical materials. One of the way to catch diseases from using chemical material is the touching skin with chemical diseases. Many common accidents occur because the skin absorb chemical materials during using it quickly leading to catching physical poisoning.   Inhalation also catch many diseases. The respiratory system one of the most system of catching diseases. Many diseases entered into body easily through the respiratory system. Most cases of diseases that happen occur during working. When people breathe gasses and vapors. Ingestion also one of the most popular way for entering chemical material in our body. The population of hands, foods, water and others help to enter poisons materials into the body. Fortunately the digestive system does not absorb all poisonous food, there are many factors help the digestive way to reduce the absorption poisons into the body. Injection one of the most famous way to inter the chem ical material in our body. When people sick, they go to doctors and they obtain medicine. Most of these medicine contain toxic substances. The needle which was filled by chemical material could be entered into the leg or arm by chance, leading to the toxic liquid enter into the body, therefore men catch many diseases. Most of these diseases called cancer and other dangerous diseases. There are many ways also to catch diseases, when people work in garage and use gas, Kerosene to put theses gases in the car, liquid gases fall into the body. These liquid gases touch the skin of the body; hence damage the body by dangerous diseases. Finally, chemical material is one of the most silence killer in our world. Chemical materials enters in all food, water and other purposes. People is the principle of spreading chemical materials around the world. Chemical materials effects badly on our life. Drugs contain many chemical materials so the prevention is better than cure. All substances, which contain chemical materials, remain for a long time in the environment. There are many ways help chemical materials to enter them to into the body such as Injection, breathing, swallowing, skin and ingestion. There are many ways should follow to prevent the spreading of chemical materials. We should build our houses fare away of agricultural lands. We should remain our place very clean. All thing must be clean to prevent the chemical materials from catching us. We should discover alternative ways to reduce the use of chemical materials. We must avoid using of toxic materials or learn how to deal with these materials. . In the end, w e should be caution to a void the hazardous chemical materials to be in good heath and to protect our future generation. References Canadian Centre for Occupational Health and Safety. (2017, Feb 14). How Do I Work Safely with Toxic Materials. Retrieved from Canadian Centre for Occupational Health and Safety: http://www.ccohs.ca/oshanswers/prevention/toxic_safe.html CHRIS DINESEN ROGERS . (2015, Aug 10). Ways to Prevent Hazardous Waste. Retrieved from Livestrong.com: http://www.livestrong.com/article/167183-ways-to-prevent-hazardous-waste/ Ckilbourne. (2012, Apr 1). Rules for Safe Handling of Hazardous Materials. Retrieved from Ehsdailyadvisor.blr.com: http://ehsdailyadvisor.blr.com/2012/04/11-rules-for-safe-handling-of-hazardous-materials/ Utah.gov. (2017, Feb 14). Hazardous Materials. Retrieved from Utah.gov: https://www.utah.gov/beready/family/HazardousMaterials.html